Article

Imbalances in China's International Payments System


Why it’s urgent that China adjust its balance of payment structure and safeguard its foreign assets
According to Geoffrey Crowther, a former chief editor of The Economist, a country’s balance of payments structure normally evolves through six phases. (1) Young debtor nation: The country runs trade and income balance deficits, and hence current account deficits. The country starts to accumulate foreign debt. (2) Mature debtor nation: The country starts to run trade surpluses. But its deficit in investment income is still larger than its trade surplus. Therefore, the country still runs current account deficits and continues to accumulate foreign debt. (3) Debt repayment nation: Because its trade surplus is larger than its deficit from investment income, the country begins to run current account surpluses and to repay its foreign debt. (4) Young creditor nation: The country runs a surplus on investment income as well as a trade surplus. Running a current account surplus means that the country is a capital exporting country, but running a surplus in investment income implies that the country has become a creditor nation. (5) Mature creditor nation: The country has started to run trade deficits. But it still runs a current account surplus, because its investment income surplus is larger than its trade deficit. (6) Credit disposition nation: The country’s trade account deficit surpasses its surplus investment income. By running current account deficits the country becomes a capital importing country. The country is still a creditor nation, but its holdings of net foreign assets are shrinking. 

Economic reality fits the Crowther model quite well. Southeast Asian developing countries were in the first phase until the Asian financial crisis. Thailand, for example, ran deficits in its trade account, investment income, and current account for decades until the Asian financial crisis. After having passed through the first three phases, Japan entered the fourth phase in 2011, when it started to run a trade deficit, while still running a current account surplus, because it enjoyed massive earnings from foreign investment income.

Nevertheless, there are two conspicuous exceptions. One is China and the other is the United States. China has run trade and current account surpluses for more than 2 decades, but its investment income has been in red for more than 10 years, although it is the third biggest creditor nation in the world. In contrast, the United States has run trade and current account deficits since the early 1980s, and is the world’s largest debtor nation. But it still runs a surplus in investment income. In Ricardo Hausmann’s metaphor, while the United States is exporting dark matter, China is importing it. 

The direct cause of the abnormality that one of the largest creditor nations runs a persistent deficit on investment income is not difficult to find. Although China has nearly $2 trillion USD net foreign assets, its assets consist mainly of US government bonds while most of its liabilities arise from Foreign Direct Investment (FDI). According to the Conference Board, American multinationals’ average investment return in China was 33 percent in 2008. In the same time period, a World Bank team found that the average investment return for multinationals in general in China was 22 percent. In contrast, in 2008, the 10-year US Treasury yield returned less than 3 percent.

China’s irrational international investment position (IIP) in turn is attributable to China’s irrational balance of payments structure, which is characterized by the so- called “twin surpluses”— surpluses on both the current and capital accounts. The twin surpluses can be understood as a result of stacking two Crowther phases together through institutional and policy distortion.

To explain this point, assume that China consists of two areas: Area I and Area II. Area I wishes to import capital goods and technology to the tune of $100 billion USD, but does not have the advantage of foreign exchange earned through trade and investment income surpluses. Area I is thus forced to raise $100 billion USD via FDI, and then use the foreign exchange to import capital goods and technology. As a result, Area I runs trade and current account deficits of $100 billion USD. It, accordingly, is in the phase of the young debtor nation.

At the same time, let us suppose that Area II has $150 billion USD spare foreign exchange left after netting its exports and imports out but with no plan to import more. Area II has no option but to sell the foreign exchange to the central bank, which in turn will use the foreign exchange to buy $150 billion USD Treasuries. Because Area II runs trade (and perhaps investment income) and current account surpluses, it is in the phase of the young creditor nation.

Combining the two areas as a whole, China runs “twin surpluses”—with a $50 billion USD current account surplus, and a $100 billion USD capital account surplus, respectively.

This balance of payment in turn translates into $150 billion USD increase in China’s foreign assets in the form of Treasuries and $100 billion USD foreign liabilities in the form of FDI. Due to the huge gap between the returns on Treasuries and FDI, even with the extra net assets of $50 billion USD, China’s investment income will be negative.

However, if Area I can borrow $100 billion USD foreign exchanges from Area II for importing capital goods and technology of $100 billion USD, China as a whole will have a current account surplus of $50 billion – and an unchanged capital account. Corresponding to this balance of payments structure, China’s foreign assets in the form of Treasuries will increase by $50 billion, with no change in its foreign liabilities. The twin surpluses disappear, and investment income for this given period of time will be positive, though moderate. To borrow John Williamson’s words, if China can “translate its capital account surplus into a current account deficit,” the twin surpluses would not exist, and China’s balance of payments structure would fit Crowther model’s fourth phase of young creditor nation well. However, in practice, it is difficult, sometimes impossible, for this situation to happen, due to various institutional and policy distortions.

First of all, due to concessional policies towards FDI emanating from all levels of the government, FDI was attracted regardless the availability of foreign exchange and the long-term costs of FDI. Secondly, due to credit controls and fragmentation of the financial system, some enterprises are denied access to renminbi credit. They attract FDI just for the purpose of converting them into the renminbi. Thirdly, a large portion of capital inflows is hot money, which certainly will not translate into a trade deficit. Fourth, capital controls and foreign exchange management hinder the efforts of enterprises that planned to import capital goods and technology to obtain foreign exchange. This was particularly true in the early stages of reform and opening up. Fifth, while the country has been running a large current account surplus, it is still too immature to take high risks to invest abroad.

Though the list of the specific causes of the “twin surpluses” can be long, ultimately, it can be attributed to one cause: the inflexibility of China’s exchange rate regime. The existence of “twin surpluses,” by definition, means that the renminbi is undervalued. If the renminbi were allowed to appreciate to reach an equilibrium level, regardless of which particular channels, the current account and capital account would have to sum to zero. This implies that China must be running a current account surplus and capital account deficit, or a current account deficit and capital account surplus, unless by chance both accounts happen to be in balance.

Since 2014, an important change to China’s balance of payments structure has happened: twin surpluses have been replaced by a current account surplus and capital account deficit. At the first sight, this might seem to deserve acclaim as success in China’s structure adjustment. However, in the Crowther model, a larger capital account deficit is accompanied by increased current account surplus. But, despite the sudden appearance of capital deficit since 2014, China’s current account surplus did not change very much. Instead what has been happening is a dramatic fall in official foreign exchange reserves on an astronomical scale. Many Chinese economists argue that this is “to keep foreign exchanges in the hand of the people,” and hence an improvement in resource allocation. If it is the case, the decrease in China’s holdings of Treasuries should be equal to the increase in net nonofficial assets. However, nobody knows how much is the increase in China’s net holdings of nonofficial assets as a result of the fall in foreign exchange reserves.

Actually, the true situation is even more worrying. By definition, for any given period of time, a country’s accumulated current account surplus should be equal to the increase in the country’s net foreign assets (NIIP). However, while China’s accumulated current account surplus was $1.28 trillion USD from 2011 to the third quarter of 2016, its net foreign assets fell by $12.4 billion USD over the same period of time. Data show that long before China’s balance of payment structure turned from “twin surpluses” to “one surplus and one deficit,” China’s net foreign assets had started to go missing. After the middle of 2014, because of the fall in foreign exchange reserves, to make up the fall and enable China’s net foreign assets become equal to the accumulated current account surplus, China’s net foreign nonofficial assets would have had to increase sharply.

However, this failed to happen. Though it is difficult to pin down the amount of the net foreign nonofficial assets that, after having converted into the US dollar, failed to show up in the international investment position table, it is safe to assume that the amount of such net foreign nonofficial assets is very large.

To put it more bluntly, while the decrease in current account surplus-to-GDP ratio is a sign of improvement in balance of payments structure, the appearance of a capital account deficit since the middle of 2014 is not. To a large extent, it reflects an unwinding of carry trade and capital flights. Capital account deficits caused by such activities cannot lead to increases in foreign assets and decrease in foreign liabilities. If in the past the challenge facing China was how to stop importing “dark matter,” now it is how to avoid “matter annihilation” as well. In order to suppress carry trades and block capital flights, besides to float the renminbi, some capital controls are inevitable. Capital account liberalization has to be conditional on flexibility of the exchange rate and progress in elimination of institutional and policy distortions.

Some in China argued that the discrepancy between the accumulated current account surpluses and the increase in net foreign assets is attributable to the effects of revaluation, changes in statistical specifications, and errors and omissions. Certainly, these factors can explain part of the discrepancy. However, to attribute a $1.3 trillion USD shortfall against a total amount of 1.7 trillion USD to technical reasons is hardly serious analysis.

In short, due to historical conditions and various distortions, China has created an irrational balance of payments structure and hence an irrational IIP structure. Now China is aging quickly. Sooner or later it has to run a large investment income surplus to offset a decreasing trade surplus or trade deficit; otherwise, it will become a debt disposition nation. Time is running out. China has to adjust its balance of payments structure and fortify the safety of its foreign assets with a great sense of urgency.

Share your perspective